Concilium Civitas Almanac 2020/2021 – Professors Paweł Bukowski and Wojciech Paczos „We Need More Progressive Taxation and a Wealth Tax to Pay for the COVID-19 Rescue Packages” –

We Need More Progressive Taxation and a Wealth Tax to Pay for the COVID-19 Rescue Packages

Paweł Bukowski and Wojciech Paczos

The return of inflation?

The COVID-19 crisis has resurrected the debate on inflation. There are good reasons to believe that it might return soon. First, the lockdown measures induced sharp contractions in aggregate supply as well as aggregate demand. Although both harm production and employment, they have opposing effects on prices – demand contractions reduce, while supply contractions increase inflation. These effects are unbalanced across the sectors of the economy. The fall in measured inflation in April and May 2020 was mainly driven by deflation in transport and clothing and a slowdown in the housing sector. This is unprecedented and likely temporary, since the transport and housing sectors were the largest contributors to the Consumer Price Index including owner occupiers’ housing costs (CPIH) inflation over the past ten years. At the same time, measured inflation in food as well as recreation and culture increased (ONS, June 2020).

Additionally, the lockdown measures induced large changes in the composition of the consumption basket. Some items – almost 15 per cent of a typical CPIH basket – are simply unavailable to purchase (ONS, June 2020), while some that are still available (petrol) are bought considerably less. Thus, Dixon (2020) argues that in the UK the official CPIH index is likely underestimating the true level of inflation.

Secondly, massive fiscal interventions in the UK and the rest of the world alike rely on national (and EU-wide) central banks providing additional emergency liquidity. In the UK, this has even taken the form of direct monetary financing of the government by the Bank of England. If successful, the fiscal intervention will mechanically increase the amount of money in circulation. The demand, however, cannot increase in tandem due to the lockdown measures. This, according to the quantitative theory of money, will lead to higher inflation: ‘When stocks and inventories run low, the price system will match the dampened quantities and stimulated spending in the usual way. Prices will rise’ (Baldwin, 2020).

Thirdly, when the lockdown is lifted, the demand will recover. Goodhart and Pradhan (2020) argue that since this will happen following a period of massive fiscal and monetary rescue packages, it may lead to a surge in inflation of more than 5 per cent. Roach (2020) suggests that this may be exacerbated by the disruptions of global supply chains and the return of off-shored manufacturing. If this becomes the ‘new normal’, it will mean higher costs of production and higher prices for final products.

We may thus expect that a successful fiscal intervention will eventually lead to an increase in inflation, if not now, then during the economic recovery. This will be good news – stable or falling prices would be a sign that the fiscal policy has not used its full potential.

Who pays the inflation tax?

Inflation, regardless of whether it is accurately reflected in the CPIH or not, is a form of wealth and income tax. It reduces the value of savings and wages in consumption units. Thus, the rescue package can be viewed as a redistribution tool: a transfer to the crisis-hit parts of the economy paid for by inflation and future taxes.

Inflation is not as egalitarian a tax as it may seem[WP1] . It mostly affects three overlapping groups. The first group are the workers whose wages do not rise as fast as inflation. Those include key workers from the public sector (nurses, doctors, first responders and teachers), whose nominal wages have been essentially frozen since 2010 due to austerity measures (Dolton 2017). Unless inflation is counterbalanced by a rise in the minimum wage, low- and mid-skilled occupations from the private sector will also be affected. This is hardly a new phenomenon – since 2007 the real median wage in the UK has contracted by 3 per cent, the largest fall in Europe after Greece (Costa and Machin 2019). The record-low levels of unionization (Farber et al. 2018) and very weak bargaining power of workers (Bell et al. 2018) suggest that this phenomenon will continue also after the COVID-19 crisis.

The impact of inflation depends on the composition of the consumption basket. Households that consume goods and services with stickier prices, such as tuition, childcare or luxury products, are relatively shielded from the general rise of prices. The recent research on US households shows that those are mostly high-income people (Cravino et al. 2020). On the other hand, the middle class is more exposed to inflation, as their spending increases relatively more when inflation strikes.

Finally, inflation matters more for people who mostly keep their savings in regular bank accounts, which now offer historically low nominal interest rates and do not shield savers against inflation. Those savers are mostly from the low and middle classes. Affluent people possess relatively more real estate and business properties as well as financial products, returns on which have historically over-compensated for inflation (Crowe 2005, Piketty 2020).

Thus, inflation is a regressive wealth and income tax – the lower the income the higher proportion of it is taxed away by inflation. This burden also disproportionately falls on frontline workers. What can be done to spread the cost of rescue packages more equitably?

Progressive income and wealth taxes

We propose a twofold solution. First, to shield frontline staff against inflation, their wages should be increased. This should be a part of a wider package of boosting spending on the NHS. The coronavirus crisis has proved that healthcare should not be treated as an expenditure, but as an investment. An investment that could have saved the economy.

Secondly, those new expenditures, as well as the new public debt that is financing the rescue packages, could be partly paid off with a new progressive tax levied on those who survived the crisis relatively unscathed. This could take the form of a wealth tax on the net worth of the top 1 per cent of the richest individuals. Landais, Saez and Zucman (April 2020) proposed an EU-wide temporary progressive wealth tax with three rates: 1 per cent of net worth above €2 million (£1.75m), 2 per cent above £8 million (€7m) and 3 per cent above €1 billion (£870m). They estimate that this new tax would pay off new debt equivalent to 10 per cent of GDP after ten years.

This solution has two key advantages. Since the wealth of the most affluent is also in substantial parts liquid, nobody will be required to sell illiquid assets (e.g. their house) to pay the tax. For instance, securities and cash constitute more than 40 per cent of the gross capital value of estates with a net value above £1 million (ONS 2­­­­­019). Secondly, a wealth tax is a tax on past rather than future streams of income. It does not distort consumption, savings, labour supply or investment decisions. Such temporary wealth taxes were introduced in many countries after the two world wars, for example in Germany, Japan and Poland. The UK almost introduced a permanent wealth tax during the Labour governments of Harold Wilson and James Callaghan in 1974–6.

Milton Friedman famously said that there is no such thing as a free lunch. Rescue packages are a necessary policy tool in the current crisis, but they do not come for free. It will be costly to save the economy and those costs, sooner or later, will have to be paid off in the form of increased taxes. The equitable spreading of this burden in the future is as important as the details of the rescue packages today. Without it, the costs will disproportionately fall onto those who are already paying the highest price today.

References

Baldwin,  Richard (2020) ‘The supply side matters: Guns versus butter, COVID-style’. November. Online: https://voxeu.org/article/supply-side-matters-guns-versus-butter-covid-style (accessed 3 September 2020).

Bell, Brian, Pawel Bukowski and Stephen Machin (2018) ‘Rent Sharing and Inclusive Growth’ CEP Discussion Paper No 1584. November 2018. Online: http://cep.lse.ac.uk/pubs/download/dp1584.pdf (accessed 3 September 2020).

Costa, Rui and Stephen Machin (2019) ‘The Labour Market’, CEP Election Analysis. Online: http://cep.lse.ac.uk/pubs/download/ea046.pdf (accessed 3 September 2020).

Cravino, Javier, Ting Lan and Andrei Levchenko (2018) ‘Differences in consumption baskets across households and the distributional consequences of monetary policy’. 16 June. Online: https://voxeu.org/article/consumption-baskets-and-distributional-consequences-monetary-policy (accessed 3 September 2020).

Crowe, Christopher (2004) ‘Inflation, Inequality and Social Conflict’. CEP Discussion Paper No 657. November. Online: http://cep.lse.ac.uk/_new/publications/series.asp?prog=CEP (accessed 3 September 2020).

Dixon, Huw (2020) ‘Will CPIH inflation understate inflation for April 2020?’. 8 May. Online: www.niesr.ac.uk/blog/will-cpih-inflation-understate-inflation-april-2020 (accessed 3 September 2020).

Dolton, Peter (2017) ‘Public Sector Wages – The Real Story’. 7 July. Online: 

www.niesr.ac.uk/blog/public-sector-wages-%E2%80%93-real-story (accessed 3 September 2020).

Farber, Henry S. , Daniel Herbst, Ilyana Kuziemko and Suresh Naidu (2018) ‘Unions and Inequality Over the Twentieth Century: New Evidence from Survey Data’. NBER Working Paper No. 24587
May 2018. Online: www.nber.org/papers/w24587 (accessed 3 September 2020).

 

Goodhart, Charles and Manoj Pradhan (2020) ‘Future imperfect after coronavirus’. 27 March. Online: https://voxeu.org/article/future-imperfect-after-coronavirus (accessed 3 September 2020).

Landais, Camille, Emmanuel Saez and Gabriel Zucman (2020) ‘A progressive European wealth tax to fund the European COVID response’. Posted: 03 April 2020. 3 April. Online: https://voxeu.org/article/progressive-european-wealth-tax-fund-european-covid-response (accessed 3 September 2020).

ONS(Office of National Statistics;2019) ‘UK Personal Wealth Statistics 2014 to 2018’. January 2019. Online: www.gov.uk/government/collections/distribution-of-personal-wealth-statistics (accessed 4 September 2020).

–– (2020) ‘Consumer price inflation, UK: May 2020. Price indices, percentage changes and weights for the different measures of consumer price inflation. 17 June. Online: www.ons.gov.uk/economy/inflationandpriceindices/bulletins/consumerpriceinflation/may2020 (accessed 3 September 2020)

Piketty, Thomas (2020) Capital and Ideology, Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press

Roach, Stephen (2020) ‘A return to 1970s stagflation is only a broken supply chain away’. 6 May. Online: www.ft.com/content/5f4ef4f6-8ad6-11ea-a109-483c62d17528 (accessed 3 September 2020)

Paweł Bukowski is a research economist [WP2] in the Centre for Economic Performance, London School of Economics and Political Science and a member of the Institute of Economics of the Polish Academy of Sciences[WP3] . He gained his PhD from the Central European University in Budapest.

Wojciech Paczos is a lecturer [WP4] in Economics at Cardiff University and a member of the Institute of Economics of the Polish Academy of Sciences. He gained his PhD from the European University Institute in Florence.

The authors are founding members of the Polish young economists expert group Prosperity for Generations. [L.P.5]